Iterated Prisoner's Dilemma - Explained
What is an Iterated Prisoner's Dilemma?
- Marketing, Advertising, Sales & PR
- Accounting, Taxation, and Reporting
- Professionalism & Career Development
-
Law, Transactions, & Risk Management
Government, Legal System, Administrative Law, & Constitutional Law Legal Disputes - Civil & Criminal Law Agency Law HR, Employment, Labor, & Discrimination Business Entities, Corporate Governance & Ownership Business Transactions, Antitrust, & Securities Law Real Estate, Personal, & Intellectual Property Commercial Law: Contract, Payments, Security Interests, & Bankruptcy Consumer Protection Insurance & Risk Management Immigration Law Environmental Protection Law Inheritance, Estates, and Trusts
- Business Management & Operations
- Economics, Finance, & Analytics
What is an Iterated Prisoner's Dilemma
In game theory, a prisoner's dilemma is a situation in a game when two players need to bargain and cooperate to achieve the biggest reward - but they might not do so. When the two players refuse to cooperate, even when it is in their best interest, a prisoner's dilemma occurs. The iterated prisoner's dilemma occurs as a result of an extended prisoner's dilemma. When the same players engage in the prisoner's dilemma more than once. In some cases, this type of prisoner's dilemma is called the "Peace-War game."
How does the Iterated Prisoner's Dilemma Work?
In an iterated prisoner's dilemma, players in a game remember the past actions of their opponent and user their behavioral tendencies to align their gaming strategy. When the same players play prisoner's dilemma repeatedly, an iterated prisoner's dilemma occurs. Given that the players are already familiar with the pattern of the opponent, they can develop a strategy that will give them the highest reward and not follow the conventional gaming strategy. The most common strategy in this dilemma is Tit-for-tat. The iterated prisoner's dilemma applies to diverse human theories, especially those relating to human integration, cooperation and trust. Through this dilemma, one can know how cooperation and trust is perceived among humans. In recent times, the iterated prisoner's dilemma is used for corporate strategy and investment strategy.
Example of the Iterated Prisoner's Dilemma Game
The illustration below is helpful in understanding the iterated prisoner's dilemma in practice; John and Jude are two best friends and were arrested for a suspected crime. Both friends are put in separate rooms (isolated) and have no way to interact with each other before they are called for interrogation. During the questioning, each of them is given a choice to implicate the other partner and be free of the charges. The outcome relies on the decision of the two parties. If Jude betrays John and vice versa, it means the one betrayed will get a long jail term while the other will be set free. If John and Jude decide to cooperate and maintain silence during the interrogation, there will be no evidence to convict the two and they are given a lesser punishment. If both of them, however, decided to betray each other, they are given heavy sentences.
Related Topics
- Market Structure
- Perfect Competition
- Bidding War
- Complements & Substitutes
- Substitution Effect
- Imperfect Competition
- Market Power
- Price Takers
- Price Makers
- Perfect Competition and Decision Making
- X-Efficiency
- Captive Market
- Contestable Market Theory
- Highest Profit Point in a Perfectly Competitive Market
- Marginal Revenue
- Using Marginal Revenue and Marginal Costs to Maximize Profit
- Marginal Revenue Curve
- Profit Margin and Average Total Cost
- Break Even Point - Cost Curve
- Shutdown Point - Cost Curve
- Short-Run Decisions Based Upon Costs in a Perfectly Competitive Market
- Marginal Costs and the Supply Curve for a Perfectively Competitive Firm
- Long-Run Average Supply (LRAS)
- Decisions to Enter or Exit a Market in the Long Run
- Long-Run Equilibrium in a Perfectly Competitive Market
- Constant, Increasing, and Decreasing Cost Industries
- Productive and Allocative Efficiency in Perfectly Competitive Markets
- Market Efficiency
- Market Inefficiency
- Pareto Efficiency
- Market Failure
- Search Theory
- Monopoly
- Natural Monopoly
- Legal Monopoly
- Bilateral Monopoly
- Promoting Innovation through Intellectual Property
- Predatory Pricing
- How Monopolists Set Price with the Demand Curve
- Total Cost and Total Revenue for a Monopolist
- Marginal Revenue and Marginal Cost for a Monopolist
- Inefficiency of Monopoly
- Perfectly Competitive Market
- Monopolistic Competition
- Duopoly
- Oligopoly
- Differentiated Products
- Perceived Demand for a Monopolistic Competitor
- Monopolistic Competitors Choose Price and Quantity
- Monopolistic Competitors and Entry
- Monopolistic Competition and Efficiency
- Cartel (Economics)
- Game Theory
- Traveler's Dilemma
- Prisoner's Dilemma
- Iterated Prisoner's Dilemma
- Nash Equilibrium
- Diner's Dilemma
- Trembling Hand Perfect Equilibrium
- Gambler's Fallacy
- Arrows Impossibility Theorem
- Backward Induction
- Tournament Theory
- Oligopoly and the Prisoner’s Dilemma
- Forcing Cooperation in a Prisoner’s Dilemma
- Cooperation and the Kinked Demand Curve
- Corporate Merger or Acquisition
- Antitrust Laws
- Herfindahl-Hirschman Index
- Concentration Ratio
- Other Approaches to Measuring Monopoly Power in an Industry
- Restrictive Practices under Antitrust Law
- Natural Monopoly
- Cost-Plus Regulation
- Price Cap Regulation
- Regulatory Capture